Monday 6 May 2024 | 02:18

Opinion: Customs Union tariffs are far from entirely driven by Russian interests

16.10.2013  |  Economy   |  Arevik Mkrtchyan, European University Institute,  
Opinion: Customs Union tariffs are far from entirely driven by Russian interests

Russia’s influence within the Customs Union between Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan is estimated to be below the level predicted by a standard economic model, Arevik Mkrtchyan claims.

This brief presented by the European University Institute, addresses the Customs Union between Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan that was established in 2010. It argues that the external tariff schedule reflects a compromise between the interests of its members rather than simple expansion of Russian influence on the CU partners, and that the reduction in trade costs due to elimination of internal borders, benefits both the members of the CU and their external trade partners. Moreover, the impact of alleviated non-tariff trade costs on trade flows is strong and significant, while the tariff impact is insignificant for all members.

The Customs Union (CU) between Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan is a rare political success in the otherwise rather mixed re-integration experience within the CIS region. In its current form, the CU provides for a common external tariff among its member states and the removal of their internal customs posts. Analysts in the East and West alike tend to portray the CU as largely a geopolitical project. However, there is disagreement about its future impact: some view it as an instrument for further regional unification and ultimately economic development; others fear that the CU will lead to more protectionism and perpetuate an inefficient economic structure inherited from the Soviet times. Clearly, which scenario will play out depends crucially on how the external tariff is set and how internal trade facilitation is addressed.

The evidence on the CU’s tariff rates appears to be mixed. Established in 2010 by Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan, the CU harmonized more than 85% of tariff lines at the outset. This meant, on average, small external tariff declines for Russia and Belarus, but lead to profound tariff increases for Kazakhstan (from an average of 6.5% in 2009 to 10.3% in 2010).

Moreover, Shepotylo (2011) found that the common tariff was to a large extent influenced by Russian tariff rates, which would support the idea that the CU is simply an expansion of Russia’s influence onto the member states. Gnutzmann and Mkrtchyan (2013) study of the common tariff determination in the CU, however, suggests that the process was more complicated than that. As mentioned above, already by 2010, 85% of tariff lines were harmonized between all member states. On the other hand, this success is partly because tariff policies were similar between the countries even before formation of the CU: 44% of the now-harmonized tariffs were at the same level in all three states by 2009. For Russia and Belarus, the tariff agreement in 2009 actually rose to 84%.

Second, further inspection of the tariffs that were harmonized after the creation of the CU shows that Kazakhstan had a significant impact on the setting of new tariff rates, and especially so in the case of specific (that is, per unit of quantity) tariffs that are typically more protectionist. In particular, Russian-specific tariffs averaged 29% in 2009 and fell to 23.5% in 2010, representing a significant drop, while Kazakh-specific tariffs went up from 14% to 22% during the same time period. This demonstrates that the common external tariff for the most protected goods was a compromised choice. Ad valorem (that is, value-based) tariffs have a much lower average rate, and were much more heavily influenced by Russian rates (as an indicator, Russian average ad valorem tariff rate was 8.8% in 2009 and only slightly lower – 8.1% in 2010). It follows that the rise in the specific tariff rate of Kazakhstan can explain almost all the increase in the average rate, but precisely these tariffs were set as a compromise.

This mixture of influences in the setting of new tariff rates would suggest that there might be strategic thinking involved in the formation of the CU rather than a simple expansion of one country’s policies into the others.

Gnutzmann and Mkrtchyan (2013) consider a standard oligopolistic model of trade bloc formation with political economy motivations in order to bring a theoretical explanation behind the observed tariff changes. They derive an estimable equation of the common external tariff as a function of individual country tariff rates before and after the formation of the CU. Converting the specific tariffs into their ad valorem equivalents, they obtain that the common tariff in a CU can be presented as a linear combination of individual member-state tariffs and a sector-specific fixed effect, with the weights of individual tariffs proportional to member states’ share in the CU economy.

Thus, the theoretical prediction involves conducting a linear estimation of the CU tariff as a function of individual past tariffs. We would expect the ratio of weights of individual past tariffs of Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan to be equal to 85/5/10 respectively based on the ratio of their economies’ sizes. This would suggest that the new tariff rates are a simple, and straightforward, weighted average of the member states tariffs. Instead, the empirically estimated weight of Russia’s tariff rate is lower than the theoretically predicted one in all considered specifications, indicating  certain concessions offered by Russia to its partners, and in particular, to Kazakhstan. Namely, various estimation strategies suggest that the new tariff rates could be explained by past individual tariffs with a ratio of weights equal to around 67/11/21 for Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan, respectively.

Another interesting finding from examining tariff changes is that, after controlling for past individual tariffs, there is a large heterogeneity between sectors. Sectors, which had more protection in one of the countries, were also more likely to have a higher tariff in the CU than predicted by that country’s weight. In particular, after controlling for the individual past tariff weights and sector dummies, having highest tariff rate among the members is a significant determinant of the CU tariff; the share of the respective member state increases by an extra 17% in the weights ratio. This effect can be explained with the same oligopolistic competition model used to explain presence of production asymmetries, since a customs union creates incentives for a mutual protectionism effect: each member country receives protection for its own industries in the partner countries in return for accepting tariffs that also protect the partners’ key industries in its own market. A customs union thus leads to higher external tariffs than a free-trade area or unilateral policy. Indeed most of the tariff increases between 2009 and 2010 took place precisely in sectors that were more protected in some of the member states than in the other.

The changes in the tariff policy, the elimination of border controls, and other alterations that came about with the CU translate into changes in trade patterns. While Russia is a prime exporter to the CU partners, the reverse is not true. This pattern prompted concerns of trade diversion towards Russia (Tarr, 2012). See Isakova and Plekhanov (2012) for supporting evidence for this (the case of Kazakhstan’s imports from China in 2010).

On the other hand, the elimination of borders could work in the opposite direction by opening the Kazakh market to firms from external countries that, before the CU, were only serving the larger Russian market. Gnutzmann and Mkrtchyan (2013) show that the change in tariffs had a small impact on trade flows, while the elimination of borders had a positive and significantly larger influence. This impact of elimination of customs checks is not observed in the trade flows of 2010 (customs posts between Kazakhstan and Russia were taken down only in July 2011) and the tariff impact dominated. The overall impact of the CU, after the 2011 trade flows have been taken into account, is estimated to not only have benefited most of the members, but also to have had a positive impact on the main external trading partners: EU, China, US and an FTA partner Ukraine.

Further research could focus on the impact on small peripheral economies, like Kyrgyzstan, that are not likely to gain from access to the larger common market but which, prior to the CU, enjoyed easy customs access to the Kazakh market. The quick calls of Kyrgyzstan (by the acting prime minister in October 2011) to join the CU suggest that it faced higher trade barriers as a result of the creation of the CU.

There are also some broader policy implications related to the global trade networks. The members of the ECU rank near the bottom of World Bank’s Trading Across Borders index, hinting at large trade costs on top of formal tariffs. The removal of the last internal customs posts – effective of July 2011 – may thus explain trade gains. By creating a larger common market for operating firms, it also gives rise to the potential for integrated supply chains in the CU area. This may in fact already be happening; a recent newspaper article (Bradsher, July 2013) discusses the rise of transit rail freight from China to Europe. After elimination of internal borders, it became economically viable to instead send trains through Kazakhstan, Russia and finally Belarus.

This brief discussed the evidence that suggests that – contrary to the common belief –the CU tariffs are far from entirely driven by Russian interests. Moreover, Russia’s influence is estimated to be below the level predicted by a standard economic model. Furthermore, the estimations suggest that the CU members’ political interests of protecting certain sectors have spilt over on the partners. Analysis of the trade flows, however, showed that these changes did not matter for trade flows as much as the changes in the non-tariff trade costs, brought by eliminating internal customs checks. What is more, the CU may bring a number of indirect benefits to its members. For example, it may enhance Kazakhstan’s bargaining power during the WTO accession by allowing referrals to existing CU commitments. The immediate activation of Kazakhstan’s negotiation process following the conclusion of the Russian negotiations suggests this may very well be the case.

References

  • Bradsher, Keith (2013, July 20), “Hauling New Treasure Along the Silk Road”, New York Times, available online:http://www.nytimes.com/2013/07/21/business/global/hauling-new-treasure-along-the-silk-road.html

  • Shepotylo, Oleksandr (2011), “Calculation of the tariff rates of Kazakhstan before and after the imposition of the customs union common external tariff in 2010.” Available as part of  World Bank (2012)

  • Gnutzmann, H. and Mkrtchyan, A. (2013).Mutual protectionism: Evidence from the customs union of Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan.  EERC Working Paper 13/11E.

  • Isakova, A. and Plekhanov, A. (2012). Customs Union and Kazakhstan’s Imports. European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, London.

  • Tarr, David G., The Eurasian Customs Union among Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan: Can It Succeed Where Its Predecessor Failed? Available at SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=2185517 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2185517

  • World Bank. 2012. Kazakhstan – Assessment of costs and benefits of the Customs Union for Kazakhstan. Washington D.C. : The Worldbank.

Other news section «Economy»

Leanid Zaika: Minsk decided to beat the Kremlin by Iranian oil
Leanid Zaika: Minsk decided to beat the Kremlin by Iranian oil
There are no strategic goals behind the purchase of Iranian oil, believes economist Leanid Zaika.
Stanislau Bagdankevich: The living standard will continue to fall in 2017, and possibly in 2018
Stanislau Bagdankevich: The living standard will continue to fall in 2017, and possibly in 2018
In 2017, Belarus will have to pay about $ 5 billion debts, which may affect the level of welfare negatively.
Leu Margolin: Industry cannot rise from its knees
Leu Margolin: Industry cannot rise from its knees
Although 30 percent of Belarusian enterprises can still be revived through urgent structural reforms.
Stanislau Bagdankevich: Next year will be harsh
Stanislau Bagdankevich: Next year will be harsh
Stagnation will continue in 2017, the standard of living will not rise, and the banking system may experience a crisis.
Andrei Yeliseyeu: Russia cannot impose quotas on the Belarusian dairy products supply
Andrei Yeliseyeu: Russia cannot impose quotas on the Belarusian dairy products supply
Belarus has already agreed to reduce the level of state support to agricultural producers in the framework of the Eurasian agreements.  
Leu Margolin: It is impossible to bring back the 500 dollars salary
Leu Margolin: It is impossible to bring back the 500 dollars salary
The authorities will start pressuring businesses to make them raise salaries.
Uladzimir Kavalkin: Drop in income? Salaries are finally becoming adequate to the economy state
Uladzimir Kavalkin: Drop in income? Salaries are finally becoming adequate to the economy state
Income may drop even a little bit more, but it will not be anything dramatic - within a few percent, expert believes.
Leu Marholin: In 2017, the probability of economic growth is close to zero
Leu Marholin: In 2017, the probability of economic growth is close to zero
In 2016, Belarusian authorities were expecting growth, too. However, the economy is going down.
EBRD will prepare five state companies for privatization
EBRD will prepare five state companies for privatization
The Belarusian government has invited the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) to prepare five large state-owned companies for privatization.
 Leu Marholin: We are heading full speed to the new nineties
 Leu Marholin: We are heading full speed to the new nineties
Regression of the Belarusian economy combined with the inertness of the government will make us recall the worst years.  
Uladzimir Kavalkin: Statistics on unemployment and real unemployment are poles apart in Belarus
Uladzimir Kavalkin: Statistics on unemployment and real unemployment are poles apart in Belarus
Officially, the unemployment in our country is reducing – if judging by the number of registrations at the labor exchange; however, the number of jobs doesn’t increase in the economy.
Leanid Zaika: Decline in prices on gas should lead to the reduction in utility costs
Leanid Zaika: Decline in prices on gas should lead to the reduction in utility costs
In the situation of cheaper prices on gas Lukashenka's decree on non-cash housing subsidies looks weird.
Point of view: Defence industry in Belarus evolved from helpless to a weighty branch of economy
Point of view: Defence industry in Belarus evolved from helpless to a weighty branch of economy
Recently Belarus State Military Industrial Committee announced that in the first half of 2016 its enterprises earned a net profit of $80m, thus over-fulfilling the assigned export plans by a quarter.
Leu Marholin: It looks like the Belarusian PM has got a fortuneteller
Leu Marholin: It looks like the Belarusian PM has got a fortuneteller
The fall of the economy will continue in 2016; we should hardly expect growth in 2017.
Why with the success abroad, Belarus’ agriculture keeps failing at home?
Why with the success abroad, Belarus’ agriculture keeps failing at home?
Poor economic conditions in the countryside, restrictions, unfair competition, inefficiency of state-owned agricultural enterprises also contribute to this ‘success story’, writes Aliaksandr Filipau.
Viktar Marhelau: We killed consumer demand inside the country
Viktar Marhelau: We killed consumer demand inside the country
In the situation of everyone’s impoverishment administrative procedures are now being perceived painfully.
Opinion: The question of what role China can play in Belarusian development remains open
Opinion: The question of what role China can play in Belarusian development remains open
On 20 June Lukashenka met with vice-chair and president of the Chinese CITIC Group Corporation Wang Jiong; it seems especially important in light of Lukashenka’s planned visit to China in September.
Lukashenka: Only lazy people don
Lukashenka: Only lazy people don't earn well in Belarus
All the conditions for everyone to be able to earn a decent salary have been enabled in Belarus, however, it is necessary to make some effort to get the money, assumes the president.
Leanid Zlotnikau: The government knows what to do with the economy, but will do nothing
Leanid Zlotnikau: The government knows what to do with the economy, but will do nothing
Belarus is losing currency earnings – in the 6 months of 2016 the country earned 3 billion less than in the same period in 2015. Instead of removing the causes of the flop the state relies on magic.
Russia
Russia's Rosatom agreed to replace reactor vessel at Belarus NPP
State Corporation Rosatom has agreed to replace reactor vessel at the Astravets NPP in Belarus.
Gintautas Mažeikis: The relation of political field and arena in the framework of information war

In his report, philosopher Gintautas Mažeikis discusses several concepts that have been a part of the European social and philosophical thought for quite a time.

“It is our big joint work”

It is impossible to change life in cities just in three years (the timeline of the “Agenda 50” campaign implementation). But changing the structure of relationships in local communities is possible.

Shhh! Belarus Wants You to Think It’s Turning Over a New Leaf

Minsk’s muddled media clampdown could jeopardize warming of relations with the West.

Mikhail Matskevich: How to create a local agenda and make it a problem solving tool

To achieve changes, you need to be interested in them and stop pinning all hopes on the state.